HomeFinancial System and RegulationUpdated summary: Shadow banking and asset management

Updated summary: Shadow banking and asset management

-

Easy monetary conditions and tighter regulation for banks naturally encourage risk transformation and liquidity creation outside the banking system. Institutional asset managers are key agents of that development. As such shadow banking relies on collateral value rather than external backstops it can make the financial system more pro-cyclical and vulnerable. The size and herding incentives of large asset managers could reinforce excesses.

This updated review is an extended part of the summary page “Financial System” (view summary page here) of this blog.

In a nutshell

Non-conventional monetary policy and regulatory tightening (view post on basics here) have reinvigorated a secular trend towards credit, maturity, and liquidity transformation outside the regulated banking system. Yield and volatility repression through central banks encourage risk transformation in general, while tighter risk and leverage limits for regulated banks motivate migration into less restricted institutions. Financial intermediation outside the regulated banking system is widely (and ominously) called “shadow banking”. Front and center of shadow banking in developed markets are institutional asset managers, which are the key suppliers and receivers of liquidity services and collateral (view post here).The rising importance of shadow banking and asset management has profound implications for financial system risk. First, liquidity services of shadow banks is dependent on collateral value (i.e. financial asset prices) and lacks an official  backstop, such a central bank or deposit insurance. This makes overall liquidity and market prices more pro-cyclical and prone to escalating dynamics (euphemism for “bubbles” and “crashes”). At the same time, asset managers’ growing systemic role is compounded by their rapid medium-term growth. The sheer size of their assets under management relative to market liquidity and their proclivity to simplistic risk management and herding, is likely to further accentuate risks of excesses.

The basics of shadow banking

Modern shadow banking denotes financial intermediation that provides large-scale risk transformation services and creates liquidity outside the regulated banking system. Shadow banks include government-sponsored entities (Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac in the U.S.), various types of investment funds, money market funds, structured finance vehicles, broker-dealers, financial holding companies, and finance companies. Commodity trading firms are sometimes viewed as peripheral members of the shadow banking system, to the extent that they act as financial intermediaries and engage in collateralized financing transactions (view post here).

Maybe the most critical function of the shadow banking system, from a systemic point of view, is to channel the cash pools of institutions, typically asset managers, via collateralized transactions to the funding of loans, bonds, and equities. Hence, in parallel to the classical deposit-based funding of bank intermediation, the shadow banking system establishes a secured transactions-based wholesale funding of non-bank intermediation (view post here).

The collateral used in these transactions has typically likewise been sourced from asset managers, in a practice that is called ‘re-use of pledged collateral’. This means that the shadow banking system has become a catalyst for the build-up of ‘collateral chains’, sequences of transaction that use the same asset for multiple securitizations. As a consequence, the role of asset managers and off-balance vehicles of banks in intermediation has greatly increased, as has the importance of asset managers as source for ‘collateral mining’.

The systemic risks of shadow banking

Unlike regulated banks, institutions labeled as shadow banks typically have no direct and explicit access to public sources of liquidity or credit backstops. This means that shadow banking only has limited capacity to absorb liquidity pressure and hence is more prone to manifest and contribute to escalatory crises (view post here). Moreover, unlike traditional money, shadow money is constrained by the value of assets that serve as collateral.

Regulators fear that shadow banking has been conducive to excessive leverage in the economy and contributed to systemic pressure through sudden stops and asset fire sales. The risk of fire sales is a particular concern in private repurchase operations (view post here), the main market for funding of securities holdings. More generally, reliance on secured financing provides a powerful channel of transmission of shocks in the financial system:

  • First, collateral values are likely to fall more than asset prices when uncertainty is rising (view post here).
  • Second, the decline in collateral values translates in additional collateral calls possibly compounded by higher haircuts and margins requirements, typical mechanisms of fire sales.

Moreover, distress in collateralized transactions could easily spill over to regulated banking activity, particularly through broker-dealer activities. In order to achieve collateral efficiency dealer banks engage in rehypothecation, And in order to minimize balance sheet usages, they use their scope for netting positions. In case of market distress and collateral value losses, dealer banks face rollover risks, which are not dissimilar to a classical deposit run (view post here).

Beyond internal risks, shadow banks may be impaired by malfunctioning markets, maybe though direct political interference and tax measures. A drastic example have been plans for the introduction of a financial transaction tax by 11 countries of the eurozone (view post here). In its original form this tax would have had a profound negative impact on investment returns and on liquidity in markets for cash products and derivatives.

Shadow banking becomes a systemic risk particularly if it grows rapidly relative to other markets and is motivated predominantly by regulatory arbitrage (view post here). These risks may end up being “put” to the public safety net, as many shadow-banking-related entities—banks, dealer banks, and (under some conditions) money market funds—benefit from implicit or explicit guarantees. These “puts” make the system effectively subsidized (view post here).

Rise and risks of institutional asset management

Large parts of financial markets are dominated by classical long-term real money institutions, such as mutual funds, pension funds, insurances, and sovereign wealth funds. Other more specialized funds have carved out niches for special purposes. Altogether, the role of professional asset management has been growing with total assets already close to USD90 trillion, roughly equal in size to global GDP.

The expansion of institutional investment is being propelled by the demographic development of the world, particularly population aging, which is for the time being is bringing the median age of the world population closer to the point of maximum saving, resulting in a growing savings glut (view post here). As a result, the importance of asset management for global liquidity (defined as ease of financing) is increasing relative to the regulated banking system, in particular through greater presence in bond markets (view post here).

As demographics and economic development propel the industry to ever higher assets under under management, self-reinforcing correlated dynamics become a greater systemic concern. Market conventions, accounting practices, regulatory changes and structural changes in the industry all contribute to this risk (view post here).

Long-term institutional investors are subject to regulation and standards that can impair the efficient allocation of assets. Also, there is evidence that these institutions can become pro-cyclical in their investment style, particularly in crises, because:

  • institutional investors tend to underestimate liquidity needs, deliberately or not;
  • risk management systems struggle with the estimation of tail risk and statistical models are usually thrown into disarray during financial turmoil (view post here);
  • investment managers follow short-term performance targets and can be compromised by human stress response (view post here);
  • regulations and conventions typically encourage herding (view post here).
  • real money funds can become a catalyst of market sell offs because they are averse to significant under-performance vis-a-vis peers or benchmarks (view post here).

Negative momentum that results from investment management can be reinforced by redemptions. Moreover, the impact of flows and prices is likely becoming stronger. In the fixed-income space, torrid growth in the size of funds has in recent years has been in stark contrast with weakening market intermediation (“market making”) by banks. This has largely been the consequence of regulatory reforms and increases the risk of severe market dislocations if and when accommodative monetary policy is to be rolled back.

Editor
Editorhttps://research.macrosynergy.com
Ralph Sueppel is managing director for research and trading strategies at Macrosynergy. He has worked in economics and finance since the early 1990s for investment banks, the European Central Bank, and leading hedge funds.